Store brands play an increasingly important role in retailing business, leading more and more retailers to introduce store brands. Abundant research focuses on competition between store brands and national brands and counterstrategies that national-brand manufacturers can take to counter store-brand introduction. A little research studies the store-brand production issue, however, all under single-retailer scenarios. To approach the real world, we employ game theory to model interaction between a national-brand manufacturer and multiple locally monopolist retailers, one of whom has capability and motivation to introduce a store brand. Five Stackelberg games are build and solved to investigate: how the presence of the non-store-brand retailers affects the store-brand retailer’s decision on and profitability in the store-brand introduction; how the store-brand retailer should arrange store-brand production; whether there is a win–win situation where both the store-brand retailer and the national-brand manufacturerare better off with the latter producing the store brand. Accordingly, our study offers a novel rationale for why so many, especially leading, national-brand manufacturers are involved in the store-brand production. Some useful managerial suggestions are proposed on the store-brand introduction and production arrangement.
Accepté le :
Première publication :
Publié le :
DOI : 10.1051/ro/2019035
Mots-clés : Game theory, private label, production outsourcing, supply chain management
@article{RO_2020__54_3_827_0, author = {Cheng, Rong and Ma, Weimin and Ke, Hua}, title = {Store-brand introduction and production arrangement in the presence of multiple retailers}, journal = {RAIRO - Operations Research - Recherche Op\'erationnelle}, pages = {827--843}, publisher = {EDP-Sciences}, volume = {54}, number = {3}, year = {2020}, doi = {10.1051/ro/2019035}, mrnumber = {4078187}, zbl = {1439.90043}, language = {en}, url = {http://archive.numdam.org/articles/10.1051/ro/2019035/} }
TY - JOUR AU - Cheng, Rong AU - Ma, Weimin AU - Ke, Hua TI - Store-brand introduction and production arrangement in the presence of multiple retailers JO - RAIRO - Operations Research - Recherche Opérationnelle PY - 2020 SP - 827 EP - 843 VL - 54 IS - 3 PB - EDP-Sciences UR - http://archive.numdam.org/articles/10.1051/ro/2019035/ DO - 10.1051/ro/2019035 LA - en ID - RO_2020__54_3_827_0 ER -
%0 Journal Article %A Cheng, Rong %A Ma, Weimin %A Ke, Hua %T Store-brand introduction and production arrangement in the presence of multiple retailers %J RAIRO - Operations Research - Recherche Opérationnelle %D 2020 %P 827-843 %V 54 %N 3 %I EDP-Sciences %U http://archive.numdam.org/articles/10.1051/ro/2019035/ %R 10.1051/ro/2019035 %G en %F RO_2020__54_3_827_0
Cheng, Rong; Ma, Weimin; Ke, Hua. Store-brand introduction and production arrangement in the presence of multiple retailers. RAIRO - Operations Research - Recherche Opérationnelle, Tome 54 (2020) no. 3, pp. 827-843. doi : 10.1051/ro/2019035. http://archive.numdam.org/articles/10.1051/ro/2019035/
[1] Aggressive or partnership strategy: which choice is better for the national brand? Int. J. Prod. Econ. 166 (2015) 50–63. | DOI
and ,[2] Is producing a private label counterproductive for a branded manufacturer? Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 39 (2012) 213–239. | DOI
and ,[3] Store loyalty, bargaining power and the private label production issue. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 33 (2006) 315–335. | DOI
,[4] Strategic effects of private labels. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 26 (1999) 147–165. | DOI
, and ,[5] Optimal production channel for private labels: too much or too little innovation? J. Econ. Manage. Strategy 24 (2015) 348–368. | DOI
, and ,[6] An empirical investigation of private label supply by national label producers. Market. Sci. 29 (2010) 738–755. | DOI
, , and ,[7] Paying customers to switch. J. Econ. Manage. Strategy 6 (1997) 877–897. | DOI
,[8] Private label positioning: quality versus feature differentiation from the national brand. J. Retail. 82 (2006) 79–93. | DOI
and ,[9] Vertical restraints and the market power of large distributors. Rev. Ind. Org. 17 (2000) 135–153. | DOI
and ,[10] The new appeal of private labels. Harvard Bus. Rev. 77 (1999) 41–48.
and ,[11] Supply chains in the presence of store brands. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 224 (2013) 392–403. | DOI | MR | Zbl
, and ,[12] Private labels, price rivalry, and public policy. Eur. Econ. Rev. 51 (2007) 403–424. | DOI
and ,[13] Vertical relationships and dual branding strategies in the italian food industry. Agribusiness 13 (1997) 185–195. | DOI
, and ,[14] Supply chain conflict due to store brands: the value of wholesale price commitment in a retail supply chain. Decis. Sci. 41 (2010) 203–230. | DOI
and ,[15] Supply chain interactions due to store-brand introductions: the impact of retail competition. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 203 (2010) 575–582. | DOI | Zbl
and ,[16] Premium store brand: product development collaboration between retailers and national brand manufacturers. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 185 (2017) 128–138. | DOI
and ,[17] An option-pricing look at the introduction of private labels. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 51 (2000) 221–230. | DOI | Zbl
,[18] Private Label Strategy: How to Meet the Store Brand Challenge. Harvard Business Review Press, Boston, MA (2007).
and ,[19] Why do leading brand manufacturers supply private labels? J. Bus. Ind. Market. 23 (2008) 273–278. | DOI
, and ,[20] House brands hit home. Market. Sci.. Retrieved January 10 (1992) (2013).
,[21] Informing, transforming, and persuading: disentangling the multiple effects of advertising on brand choice decisions. Market. Sci. 27 (2008) 334–355. | DOI
, and ,[22] Why retailers sell private labels. J. Econ. Manage. Strategy 4 (1995) 509–528. | DOI
,[23] Private labels and manufacturer counterstrategies. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 26 (1999) 125–145. | DOI
,[24] The strategic positioning of store brands in retailer–manufacturer negotiations, Rev. Ind. Org. 24 (2004) 161–194. | DOI
and ,[25] Private labels and the channel relationship: a cross-category analysis. J. Bus. 71 (1998) 573–600. | DOI
and ,[26] Nielsen, The state of private label around the world. Available from: https://www.nielsen.com/us/en/insights/report/2014/the-state-of-private-label-around-the-world/ (2014).
[27] PLMA, Private label today. Available from: http://www.plmainternational.com/industry-news/private-label-today (2016).
[28] PLMA-Show, Plma’s 2016 private label trade show. Available from: http://plma.com/showinfo/showinfo2016.html (2016).
[29] Brands versus private labels: fighting to win. Harvard Bus. Rev. 74 (1996) 99–110.
and ,[30] The introduction and performance of store brands. Manage. Sci. 41 (1995) 957–978. | DOI
, and ,[31] Positioning of store brands. Market. Sci. 21 (2002) 378–397. | DOI
, and ,[32] Private label strategies-myths and realities. In: Handbook of Marketing Strategy (2012) 318–335.
and ,[33] Assessing the external validity of analytical results from national brand and store brand competition models. Market. Sci. 28 (2009) 759–781. | DOI
,[34] Determinants of store brand share. J. Retail. 90 (2014) 141–153. | DOI
and ,[35] Manufacturer and retailer strategies to impact store brand share: global integration, local adaptation, and worldwide learning. Market. Sci. 33 (2013) 6–26. | DOI
and ,[36] Category management-a pervasive, new vertical/horizontal format. Antitrust 15 (2000) 77.
,[37] The nature and benefits of national brand/private label competition. Rev. Ind. Org. 24 (2004) 105–127. | DOI
,[38] Should national brand manufacturers produce private labels? J. Model. Manage. 2 (2007) 56–70. | DOI
,[39] Does private-label production by national-brand manufacturers create discounter goodwill? Int. J. Res. Market. 30 (2013) 343–357. | DOI
, , and ,[40] A positive theory of private label: a strategic role of private label in a duopoly national-brand market. Market. Lett. 16 (2005) 143–161. | DOI
and ,Cité par Sources :